Kofi Adjepong- Boateng Millionaire Entrepreneur


Kofi Adjepong- Boateng is an investment banker and Senior Associate Member of St. Antony’s College, Oxford. Prior to co-founding First Africa in 1996, he worked in the corporate finance, trade finance and government advisory fields in Africa with SG Warburg & Co., HSBC Equator and Price Waterhouse. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, he was involved in a number of sovereign debt buy-backs, corporate restructurings and commodity financings which occurred in Africa; and since the late 1990s, he has advised on several of Africa’s largest corporate transactions.

During 2003 and 2004, he served on the Africa Policy Advisory Panel, an advisory group mandated by the U.S. Congress, which reported to Colin Powell, the U.S. Secretary of State. He currently serves as a member of the Policy Committee of The Centre for the Study of African Economies (CSAE) and sits on CSAE’s Finance Committee. He is also a member of the Steering Committee of a research project at the Lauterpacht Centre for International Law at the University of Cambridge which is looking into the legal issues associated with accusations of corporate complicity in human rights abuse in resource rich countries. Since 2006, he has served on the International Advisory Board of ACE Ltd, the world’s largest insurer of political risk.

He is a Fellow of the Royal Society of Arts and Manufacturers in the UK and a Member of the UK’s Royal Economic Society.


Introductory remarks


I am grateful to Paul, Stefan and the Centre for inviting me here this morning to give this opening address.


I suppose I ought to tell you a bit about myself. I grew up in Ghana, studied at this University many years ago, and have spent my entire career in investment banking. I spent the early part of my career working in London on corporate and sovereign restructurings (including debt restructurings and early privatisations). In 1993, I set up an investment bank in Kenya called Loita Capital Partners which I left in 1995. In 1996, about 13 years ago, a colleague and I established a joint venture investment bank with S.G Warburg & Co. which was at the time the UKs largest and most successful investment bank. That firm, First Africa, was recently acquired by the Standard Chartered Bank group. Standard Chartered has built one of the largest banking operations in Africa over the last 150 years.


I should state upfront that I don’t know very much about what most of you know a lot about. I am not a professional economist; nor am I a civil servant active in policy formation. However, I do know something about “money” and about why, from time to time, it moves from one place to another.. This is probably why I have been asked by Stefan to speak on Africa and the banking crisis”. It seems to me there that are two ways to approach this subject.


One way is to discuss the likely effects on the continent’s growth of the reduction in imports by Africa’s trading partners or the effects on Africa’s trade finance of either a contraction in, or rise of the costs of, global trade finance as international banks come under pressure to focus on their home markets1. I could, for example, talk about the effects of a fall in commodity prices on Africa’s growth. In his recent article in this month’s edition of the UK’s Prospect magazine, Paul Collier estimates that over 200,000 jobs have been lost in the DRC as a result of the collapse in cobalt prices and that South Africa is expecting to lose around 50,000 jobs in its mining sector2

Slow global growth will have implications for African growth and there is quite a bit that one could say about this aspect of the global crisis. But, judging by the quality of this audience, you have probably forgotten more than I will ever know about the inter-relationship between global economic growth and Africa’s trade fortunes. For this reason, I will not spend any time this morning talking to you about this as I feel I can add little to your understanding of this area of international economics and trade. Instead, I have prepared a short slide presentation which is available as a take away and will be sent by Rose Page, Pauls assistant, to each of you by email. It contains a number of the statistics which highlight the current global predicament. What these statistics show in summary is that we are in a very deep global recession comparable by economic historians to the 1930s Depression in certain of its characteristics and from which no country in Africa is immune. No matter how long I take to say this that will be my conclusion so it makes sense to state this conclusion up front and move on.


The second approach to tackling this topic is to ask the question: “What should we (and by that I mean “you and I”) focus on to prepare African policy makers for a post-recession world knowing the likely effects that this global slowdown will have on African economies?” I’d like to find a way in these opening remarks to combine my experience as an investment banker with yours as central bankers and research economists and to see whether there are areas of mutual interest to which we should give attention in the next few months and years in order to ensure that some good comes out of the banking crisis for the benefit of the poor, the middle class and (dare I say it) the rich who inhabit our continent.


One of the advantages about giving a talk to an academic audience is the comfort of knowing that all the parties present are here, not only to share what they know, but also to find out what they don’t know. “Not knowing” at conferences like this is almost as important as “knowing”. I want to spend some time this morning talking about what we do know, but also, would like to invite you, the audience, at the end of this session to help, through questions, shape a research agenda to address what we “don’t know” but should. In this context, the comment that what I have to say “raises more questions than answers” will be seen, by me at least, as a compliment!


I suppose I ought to say upfront that I will be drawing on certain aspects of the history of economics to draw some of my conclusions. This is an important point as, given the current state of the world economy, we are hearing a lot about “history” in general and the 1930s Depression in particular. I recognise the importance in the social sciences of the separation nowadays between “economic history” and “economic theory”.Unlike some, I have always felt that this separation is unfortunate and one of the benefits, if one can describe it as such, of the current crisis is the fact that a lot of the commentary on the current state of affairs is drawing somewhat liberally on economic history as well as the history of economic thought3.


3 Partha Dasgupta draws attention to this unfortunate separation between economic theory and econom ic history in the introduction to a paper presented in 1998. He writes: “You can emerge from your graduate studies in economics without having read any of the classics, or indeed, without having anything other than a vague notion of what the great thinkers of the past had written. The modern economist doesn’t even try to legitimize his inquiry by linking it to questions addressed in the canon; he typically begins his article by referring to something in the literature a few months old. He reads Ricardo no more than the contemporary physicist reads James Clerk Maxwell. What today’s economic student gets of the classics are those bits that have survived the textbook treatment, dressed in modern garb. The history of economic ideas hasn’t died; it has simply metamorphosed into a specialized field.


3






I have been an investment banker for over twenty years. In that period, my career has been influenced by:


-                       the “Third World debt” crisis which had its origins in the Mexican default in 1982. My career started in 1988 about 6 years after the onset of the Mexican crisis. Not surprisingly, all of my assignments in the early days were related in some way to the restructuring African sovereign debt;
-                       the stock market crash of 1987;
-                       the US savings and loan debacle; -     the Asian crisis;
-                       the Russian crisis and the implosion of LTCM; -        the tech bubble of 2000; and now
-                       the current global financial crisis.


That’s seven events of global financial significance all of which occurred in the last twenty-five or so years. Each event taught us important lessons and gave rise to academic research and a body of literature that is still contributing to our understanding today of how financial markets work.


First Africa, the firm I co-founded, has been fortunate to have had a ring-side seat during this in which the African capital markets have grown and evolved rapidly. We have had extraordinary people work with the firm during this time, all of whom were involved in ground-breaking transactions. Some of the precedents in which the firm has been involved include:


-           The sale by Anglo American Corporation in 1995 of JCI Limited to a Black Economic Empowerment consortium in South Africa. At the time, JCI was the world’s sixth largest gold company and the transaction was the most important of the BEE mining transactions completed in South Africa in that year;


-           The sale by the Anglo American Group in 1996 of its interest in First Merchant Bank of Zimbabwe. This was one of the first “empowerment” transactions in Zimbabwe and led to the creation of what has become one of Southern Africa’s important regional banking groups, the African Banking Corporation;


-           In 1999, we acted as an adviser on the takeover of the Cotton Company of Zimbabwe by a private equity consortium. This transaction involved the takeover of what was at the time Zimbabwes largest agricultural company;



It is taught, but it is not compulsory for students, at least not in the major economics departments. And just as most working economists today know little of the ideas that have shaped their subject, your average historian of economic thought understands little of what is currently going on in economics and why. The separation is as complete as can be” Partha Dasgupta, Modern Economics and its Critics I, St. John’s College (February 1998) University of Cambridge, England.


4




-           In 2003, we acted on the sale of the Social Security Bank in Ghana to Frances Societe Generale. This transaction involved us in what became the first takeover of a listed bank anywhere in sub-Saharan Africa;


-           In 2004, the firm acted as an adviser to Anglogold on its merger with Ashanti Goldfields Company. This merger created Africa’s largest gold company. The transaction was accompanied by the dual listing of the merged entity in South Africa and Ghana and remains to date, the largest takeover of a listed West African company;


-           In 2005, we acted on the reverse takeover of African Gold by Mwana Resources and the listing of Mwana on AIM in London. Reversing predominantly Zimbabwean assets in a London listed vehicle is difficult at the best of times. To do so at the height of the Zimbabwean crisis was ground breaking in its own right;


-           In 2006, we advised the MTN Group on its acquisition of Investcom LLC. This was one of the most important cross-border takovers by a South African company and at the time, was the second largest transaction of its kind in South Africa. It was also the first takeover of a company listed on the Dubai Stock Exchange and is still the only successful transaction of this size completed by either of the leading South Africa telecoms companies;


-           We acted on the conversion of Equity Building Society in East Africa from a mutual society into a bank and the listing of Equity Bank on the Nairobi Stock Exchange. This transaction was the first of its kind in East Africa and has since become the precedent for those considering transactions of this kind; and


-           More recently, we acted in 2008 and early this year on the Rights Issue and Placing undertaken by ETI, the West African regional banking group. This transaction raised a significant sum for the bank and was executed during the still ongoing global financial crisis. ETI raised what amounted the largest pool of capital raised by any firm on the Ghana Stock Exchange, which is one of the West African exchanges on which the bank is listed.


The above list illustrates the breadth of work carried out by firms such as mine in Africa. There are many other transactions which could be added to this list but I believe the short list above illustrates the extent to which financial services companies such as ours play an important role in facilitating the corporate activity in Africa. The question worth considering is the extent to which this level of corporate activity took place primarily because of financial innovations in Africa and elsewhere. Innovations such as the introduction of stock markets, the role played by private equity and hedge funds in investing in African companies and the emergence of cross-border financial players who have been able to help ensure that standardised and good quality financial information becomes available outside of national borders are all important




5




financial innovations whose role in spawning cross-border corporate activity should not be underestimated.


Over time, today’s crisis will give rise to robust debate amongst professional economists such as you about the policy prescriptions for a post-recession world and I would like to use these opening remarks to ask that you start thinking about areas for further research which will make more robust about our approach to policy. That’s my objective this morning.


So, What are Bankers for…(in theory!)


Many economists, and I hope the majority of you here, view freely operating markets in which free exchange occurs as the best mechanism for allocating scarce resources. From the point of view of allocating capital, the most important markets in this respect are the commercial banking market, stock exchange (or stock market) and other capital markets, such as the bond market or the markets in other financial securities.


I share the view that the capital markets are crucial for the allocation of resources in a modern economy. Household savings are channelled through the capital markets to the corporate sector and investment funds are allocated, again through the markets, among companies. Markets allow both companies and households to share risks, or so we believe. I am conscious that there have been recent lessons learnt about risk sharing as a result of the predicament in which giant global financial services companies such as AIG find themselves. But for now, I will restate my belief that well functioning capital markets enable both firms and households to share risks.


However, having said this, it seems to me on reading the literature that there are at least four important limitations to the efficiency with which capital markets operate, particularly in Africa and other emerging markets:


1. Firstly, in most countries, such as those in Africa, stock markets are not that large or important. The financial markets in Africa and other emerging markets are primarily markets for government debt. Often, the external capital that industry requires for investment is obtained in the form of loans directly from commercial banks;


2. Secondly, in all countries, including the US and UK, internally generated funds tend to be more important than is frequently acknowledged. In most African countries these internally generated funds are far more important than the external finance raised through the capital markets and commercial banks. This has certain implications which I will come back to;


3. Thirdly, the ideal of a frictionless capital market is rarely, if ever, achieved in practice. Financial intermediaries, such as stock brokers, investment and merchant banks like ours, are needed to overcome the barriers to information and to market participation. Reducing these informational barriers is important if firms and investors are to exploit markets effectively; and





6




4. Finally, we should not underestimate how important it is to well functioning capital markets that there is also an effective market in corporate control (in other words, a market in takeovers or mergers). Most of my career has been spent in the market for corporate control. This is an important aspect of the role played by the capital markets which must not be forgotten. Corporate takeovers are not as common in Africa as they are elsewhere in the world, but they are becoming more common. The possibility of takeovers is assumed to be a device for disciplining managers. An acquirer can buy up the shares of a badly managed target, replace the incumbent management, better utilise the company’s assets and make a capital gain. The capital markets are meant to play an important oversight role, but we should not ignore the equal importance of the role played in asset allocation by the threat and presence of corporate takovers.


Despite the limitations listed above, there is almost universal popularity of capital markets across the world4. To date, several African countries have introduced legislation to encourage the emergence of stock exchanges and a number of African countries have recently tapped the international bond markets. One of First Africa’s board directors, Walter Kansteiner, put in place a program when he was President Bush’s Assistant Secretary of State for Africa to encourage the rating of African sovereign bonds. Between March 2004 and February 2009, eight African countries, all of which benefited under the Kansteiner program and secured ratings, raised over US$16 billion in the international bond markets.


There are two important reasons why there is almost universal popularity of capital markets across the world. One reason is what I call the “push” factor and the other, the “pull” factor:


1. Firstly, government intervention has become discredited. The appeal of government intervention in the 1950s and 1960s had its origins in the market failures associated with the 1929 Wall Street crash and the Great Depression of the 1930s. This is an important point as it serves as a reminder that this is not the first time that a global financial crisis has led to calls for greater government intervention and regulation. Prior to the onset of the current global financial crisis, it appeared to many people that government failures are at least as important, if not more important, a problem as market failures. This is what I would call the “push” factor underpinning the popularity of the free market in general, and of capital markets in particular. The current crisis may have damped the public’s enthusiasm for free markets. Bank nationalisation in the West has been taken in its stride;


2. The second reason for the universal popularity of capital markets is that policy makers have been persuaded by economic theorists to promote free markets. Economic theory, particularly that pertaining to financial markets, has stressed the effectiveness of markets in allocating resources. This is what I would call

the “pull factor”. The general acceptance by policy makers of free markets as “efficient” markets was predominately a backlash against the views of Keynes which had initially dominated the post-war era. The intellectual attractiveness of efficient markets had a lot to do with the works of Milton Friedman, Robert Lucas and Eugene Fama. Works with which I’m sure you are all familiar.5


As economists, you are looking to understand the role that financial markets play in different national economies. As economists, you bring to your task an intellectual training that places markets at the very centre of the study of economics. Some of you might even go so far as to argue that markets define the very subject matter of economics and that complete and competitive markets represent the ideal allocation system backed up by the fundamental theorems of welfare economics.


Having said this, I am sure that most of you will recognise that there are a number of areas of study and research that have become an increasingly important part of economics in the past few decades. The current global crisis reminds us of how important these areas of study are:


1.         Firstly, there are the incentive problems that arise between agents and principals, employers and employees, managers and shareholders, financial institutions and their customers;
2.         Secondly, there are difficulties that arise in financial markets when information is asymmetrically distributed. The early work of Joe Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss helped formulate our early understanding of these issues6;
3.         Thirdly, there are always transaction costs. That’s how I have earned my living for several years. It is these transaction costs which prevent the existence of more than a small fraction of the number of possible


5                      For a discussion on the emergence of Chicago economics and the role that this school played in the providing the theoretical underpinnings to deregulation see Johan Van Overtveldt, The Chicago School How the University of Chicago Assembled the Thinkers who Revolutionized Economics and Business (Agate, 2007) and Craig F. Freedman, Chicago Fundamentalism Ideology and Methodology in Economics (World Scientific Publishing Co. (2008)). The views of the Chicago School differed radically from those of Keynes which had dominated the post-War era. Peter Clark’s review of Robert Skidelsky’s biographies of Keynes reminds us how different these two schools actually were”Skidelsky is against the single-book” interpretation of Keynesianism, and thus demands due attention for the Treatise [on Money]. Its message is that savings and investment, being different activities carried on by different people, could not simply be presumed identical. It took interest rate to bring them into equilibrium. …What Skidelsky …. chooses to emphasize is the Treatise’s preoccupation with the economics of disequilibrium, when the economy is in a position of sub-optimal output and hence unemployment. If the Bank rate …is what restores equilibrium, it follows that banking policy plays a crucial role in stabilizing the system. “Order has to be created”, is Skidelsky’s gloss; “it is not natural. Put like thisthe Treatise carries us a long way into the world disclosed by the General Theory, in which the absence of any self-righting forces in the economy is affirmed” – Peter Clark, Keynes rediscovered, Times Literary Supplement (November 20, 1992) pg 4. This is a point on which Clark had elaborated upon in his earlier and more extensive work: The Keynesian Revolution in the Making 1924-1936 (Oxford University Press (1988)) See for example pages 22-24.

6                       See, for example, J. Stiglitz and A. Weiss, Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information, (American Economic Review, 71 (3) (June) 1981;



8




markets envisaged by the Arrow-Debreu-Mackenzie general equilibrium models7;
4.         Finally, there are the long-term relationships between financial institutions and our customers which, from time to time, stifle competition and almost certainly counter any view that “perfect competition” exists.


The four areas of study listed above are central to our understanding of finance today, since much of financial practice and theory deals with the attempt to overcome agency problems, incomplete markets, transaction costs, and lack of information. Work done by two of CSAE’s Directors, Stefan Dercon on insurance markets and Marcel Fafchamps on market institutions, both highlight the shortcomings of markets and how these limitations influence institutional developments8.


Despite the above limitations, the classical theory makes a powerful case for the role that markets play in national economies whenever the imperfections caused by market power, asymmetric information, and incentive problems are not too overbearing. However, the fact that we are living through a global crisis which has largely been caused by a wide range of market failures (particularly as they relate to the incentive problems in the banking industry) is a very rude reminder of the limitations of markets.


So, why is understanding these limitations important to understanding the likely impact of the global recession on Africa’s growth?


To begin to understand the likely impact of the global crisis on Africa, one must start with an understanding of the relationship between the financial system of a country and the real economy and in particular the corporate sector.


Companies are the issuers of all of the securities traded in the capital markets outside of government paper and the investment return on these securities depend on the performance of the issuers that make up the corporate sector. The financial sector plays an important role in corporate governance because it allocates control rights (including rights over cash flows) and assists in the design of the securities that are issued. Once securities are issued, it is the financial intermediaries who provide information on company performance that investors utilise to make decisions on whether to buy or sell securities.

9





As mentioned earlier, the market for corporate control simply does not exist in most African countries, and the evidence for the monitoring role of banks over African corporates is weak. In addition, the reliance on internal finance by African corporates means that managers are largely autonomous of outside sources of capital. African firms, particularly the large diversified companies such as Dangote Industries in Nigeria or the Anglo American Group in South Africa can act as financial institutions to compensate for the limitations of financial markets and financial intermediaries. I have not as yet seen any research from you or your peers on the efficiency of capital allocation decisions made by our African conglomerates either historically (as companies such as Anglo can no longer be called conglomerates in the classical sense of the word) or presently (and here I’m thinking of the likes of Dangote in Nigeria, Press Holdings in Malawi or the various East African groups). Perhaps, this is one of the research takeaways that will come out of this conference9. I hope so.


Where capital markets are robust and deep, it is reasonable to assume that companies pay all their earnings to their shareholders and that the capital markets and the banking sector provide firms with the capital required for investment. In practice, however, features such as asymmetric information and agency costs restrict the role of external finance. This makes raising external capital a costly alternative to internally generated funds.


In several markets, including those in Africa, the development of the capital markets was stunted by the frequency with which governments print money. By printing money, governments avoided the need to issue paper which is an important component in the development of any capital markets. The inflationary effects of excesses in money supply also discouraged the purchase of long term securities. For this reason, companies operating in Africa have historically been forced to rely on internal finance as a more important source of funds than debt or equity for long term investment as the issue of long dated securities simply does not happen. The problem with this state of affairs is that there does not seem to me to be a robust reason for believing that the allocation of funds for investment that results from the use of






internally generated capital is optimal. Firms that are cash rich may be poor in opportunities for investment and vice versa and so the external finance constraint (in other words, the absence of properly functioning capital markets) appears to be a source of inefficiency. As credit becomes scarce, this problem is exacerbated. An efficient market in corporate control reduces this constraint by enabling cash rich firms to buy firms with little cash and cash poor firms to sell themselves to those with more cash. My point here is that the fact that we are beginning to see a rise in corporate takeovers and merger activity in Africa supported by the role played by investment bankers means that some of the limitations our countries face as a result of not having very deep capital markets may now start to be addressed. Research done in this area in Africa may also give rise to some interesting results and I would encourage this as another takeaway from this conference.


So what do Bankers do…(in practice!)?


The points made above highlight the importance of the role played by financial intermediaries. Despite what you might read about investment bankers, we actually do serve a useful purpose, once in a while. Financial intermediaries, (people like me), are becoming increasingly essential to the efficient exploitation of complex capital markets.


The role of financial intermediaries such as investment bankers is to make it possible for individuals to gain some of the benefits of complex financial markets without bearing all of the prohibitive costs that come with a high level of sophistication. These benefits in part arise by economizing on the costs of acquiring information. This is the traditional advising role of intermediaries such as investment bankers. The intermediary acquires information at a fixed cost and shares it with its customers at a nominal marginal cost.


Without intermediaries, the full benefits of financial innovation will not flow through to the economy at large, either globally or locally.


The analysis of the benefits to economic growth of a well-functioning financing system has a long history with a growing body of academic research arguing that the development of financial markets and institutions within countries and across borders is a critical part of the growth process and not simply an inconsequential spill over responding passively to economic growth and industrialization. Research in this area can be traced back to Walter Bagehot whose seminal work was published in 187310. The work done by Sir John Hicks in interpreting various aspects of economic history11 and by Ronald McKinnon12 on the role of capital in economic development follows this tradition. More recent research work has been carried out by several others13. This literature describes the way financial systems reduce information and

transaction costs and in so doing influence savings rates, investment decisions, technological innovations, long-run growth rates and the rate of industrialization.


Economists hold very divergent opinions on the importance of the financial system for economic growth. Walter Bagehot (1873) and Sir John Hicks (1969) argue that it played a critical role in igniting industrialisation in England by facilitating the mobilisation of capital for (what John Hicks called) “immense works”. Sir John argued that the capital market improvements that mitigated liquidity risk were the primary causes of the industrial revolution in England14. With liquid capital markets, savers can hold assets – such as equities or bonds – that they can sell quickly and easily if they want access to their savings. Simultaneously, capital markets transform these liquid financial assets into long-term capital investments in illiquid production processes. John Hicks believed that because the industrial revolution required large commitments of capital for long periods, the transformation in industry in England may not have occurred without this liquidity transformation brought about by financial innovation.


Another economist of old, Joseph Schumpeter made the point in 1912 that a well-functioning capital market spurs technological innovation by identifying and funding those ideas with the best chance of successfully implementing innovative products and/or production processes.


In contrast, Joan Robinson at Cambridge wrote in 1952 that she believed that “where enterprise leads finance follows”. According to this view, economic development creates demands for particular types of financial arrangements, and the financial system responds automatically to these demands. From what I have witnessed in my career, I am more persuaded by the views of John Hicks on the role of financial intermediaries than I am by those of Joan Robinson on this subject15. This is a point to which I will return in my conclusion.





Money, Credit, Banking, August 1988 pp 559-88; and Franklin Allen and Douglas Gale, Comparing Financial Systems, MIT Press (2000).

14                     Hicks tells readers that: “My Theory of Economic History is largely an attempt to see the main lines of economic development as a matter of the evolution of the merchant-intermediary, and its consequences”; John Hicks: The Formation of an Economist. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, September, 1979.

15                    Joan Robinson’s own views on Hick’s work are perhaps partly summarised in the following quote: “Whenever equilibrium theory is breached, economists rush like bees whose comb has been broken to patch up the damage. J. R. Hicks was one of the first, with his IS/LM, to try to reduce the General Theory to a system of equilibrium. This had a wide success and has distorted teaching for many generations of students. J.R.Hicks used to be fond of quoting a letter from Keynes which, because of its friendly tone, seemed to approve of IS/LM, but it contained a clear objection to a system that leaves out expectations of the future from the inducements to invest…Forty years later, John Hicks noticed the difference between the future and the past and became dissatisfied with IS/LM but (presumably to save face for his predecessor, J.R.) he argued that Keynes’s analysis was only half in time and half in equilibrium” Joan Robinson, Further Contributions to Modern Economics (Basil Blackwell (1980)) pg 79.



12





Where to from here?


To my mind, taking the points I have made this morning, the current global crisis does give us a firm basis for thinking about a research agenda into the functioning of the banking and broader financial markets in Africa. It is towards this research agenda that I would like to make some suggestions.


I will make a number of points in summary form and I trust that as I do so, you remember my earlier plea for the compliment that “I have raised more questions than answers”!:


1.         Firstly, the current global crisis has given rise to significant state ownership of, or investment in, a number of the leading global banks which are active in trade and corporate finance in Africa. The likes of Citibank, Royal Bank of Scotland and Fortis will find that they come under pressure to focus on their home markets in the US, UK and Europe. Any expansion of their activities in emerging markets such as Africa will be curtailed. The likes of Barclays may not have taken state aid to date, but I expect them and those of the other banks which may also not have taken state aid to nonetheless come under pressure from their respective governments to focus on business in their home markets. For the past two centuries, much of the flow of investment capital into Africa and other emerging markets has been dominated by international merchant banks. It is these banks which shaped the early pattern of global investment into Africa. A fair amount of research exists at present on the nature of, and mechanisms for, investment made through the British capital markets into Argentina, Australia, Canada, and the United States16 but less so in the case of Africa. The four countries mentioned above are estimated to account for about one-half of British overseas finance, were frontier territories whose development depended on their ability to bring new lands and natural resources within the scope of the international market. In this respect, these colonies were no different from those in Africa. To facilitate the economic development of the Americas and Australia, it was necessary to invest in transport, mining, land development, agriculture, agricultural and mineral processing, as well as services and products which supported colonial development. While research into these four territories exists, there has been very little research on the nature of investment into Africa during the colonial period. In this regard, it is worthwhile drawing attention to the similar historical role that the merchant banks17, such as


16                     See Lance E. Davis and Robert E. Gallman: Evolving Financial Markets and International Capital Flows- Britain, The Americas, and Australia, 1865-1914. Cambridge University Press. (2001).

17                    The definition of what constituted a “merchant bank” during the 19th Century is itself an area of some debate. Geoffrey Jones, writing on this subject, notes as follows: “The relationship between trading companies and banks was both multifaceted and highly significant for both parties. …[I]n their origins merchants and bankers were virtually indistinguishable, and it was only slowly over the course of the nineteenth century that a clearer separation occurred. In several cases, such as Anthony Gibbs, Wallace Brothers, and Mathesons, merchant banking remained part of the business portfolio. Matheson & Co. regarded its legal status in a


13




Baring Brothers & Co., N.M. Rothschild & Sons and J. Henry Schroder & Co18., played in the colonial era in facilitating capital flows into Africa as well as the role played by other members of the London Stock Exchange19. The flow of capital into Africa and other colonial territories facilitated by the London firms was the building block for today’s global financial architecture and an important component of global financial flows which continues to remain in place today20.


The withdrawal of the global banks from building their business aggressively in Africa and other emerging markets will make room for local banks to expand and capture market share. How local firms behave in the face of less competition from foreign firms will be important in

determining how deep the provision of financial services in Africa continues to become.. Will the less competitive landscape locally for both management talent and customers mean that we will see local banks expand into disciplines like project finance and corporate finance which have been the domain of foreign banks? Will they attempt to expand their product offering to the unbanked market on the back of the rising profitability of their core businesses? How prepared are our central banks to regulate the movement by our local banks into areas such as project and acquisition finance and securities (margin) lending? All these areas of banking have in the past been dominated by foreign firms.


2.         Secondly, there will be a decline in the overseas interest in acquiring African corporate assets as a result of the crisis. Over the past few years, my firm and others have seen an increase in cross-border acquisitions. The slides you will be receiving after this presentation set out data on mergers and acquisitions. Interest has been led by Asian buyers. For example, following the withdrawal of Anglo American from the Zambian Copperbelt in the early 1990s, we saw the fortunes of the Copperbelt transformed by the likes of First Quantum, Equinox and Vadanta all junior mining companies with origins in Australasia. As I explained earlier, mergers and acquisitions play an important role in unlocking corporate assets and from time to time play the efficiency role that the lack of depth in the capital markets leaves unfilled. If, as expected, the global slowdown reduces the ability of financial intermediaries to facilitate activity in Africa’s corporate sector by overseas buyers, will our capital markets respond with enough acumen to support acquisitions by our local players as they look to take advantage lower prices for corporate assets due to lower foreign interest? Again, are our regulators sufficiently tuned into the benefits of corporate consolidation and the role that our local financial services companies are to play in this area? The ties between international investment, economic growth and the role of financial intermediaries in the 19th and early 20th centuries is well documented21. These functions include facilitating the trading of risk, allocating capital between Great Britain and its colonies in Africa, monitoring managers such as Cecil John Rhodes and the United Africa Company, mobilizing savings in Britain for investment overseas, and easing the trading of goods, services, and financial contracts across borders22. In understanding these ties, it is


important to point out that academic economists and historians have highlighted some of the shortcomings associated with the role played by banks in resource allocation. The potential for banks to extract oligopolistic rents from industry is already the subject of research23.Nonetheless, the role played by investment banks is central to a well functioning M&A market and it will be important to see whether as there is a reduction in the number of foreign buyers active in Africas corporate market, the large local and regional players become more active, with support from the local African financial markets.


3.         Thirdly, the global slowdown will limit the growth by Africa’s local corporates of internally generated earnings. As mentioned earlier, retained earnings are an important, though not perfect, substitute for a deep capital market. Because of this, my expectation is that the effects of slower corporate earnings growth will translate into slower long term investment. Our financial markets are not yet deep enough to step into this gap and in the absence of alternatives, we should expect the current crisis to lead to a slow down in the very forms of long term investment that Africa needs. This need not be the case and before I conclude these opening remarks, I would like to spend a few minutes talking about one of the financial innovations that arose out of the 1930s Depression. It is a good guide to the influence that economists and Central Bankers can have on a post-recession world.,


My comments are on a company called Industrial and Commercial Finance Corporation (otherwise known as “ICFC”). It was formed in the UK after the 1930s depression. I have a soft spot for ICFC as my father worked there after his undergraduate degree at Wharton.


ICFC, was, in essence, what we would today call a “venture capital fund”. It has since evolved into 3i, a “private equity fund” and although I recognise the difference between the two types of institutions, the points that I would like to make in this presentation are common to both “venture capital” and “private equity” and so, for this reason, I will refer to the whole asset class as “private equity”.


Private Equity consists of equity investments in companies that are not listed on a stock exchange. For Africa, this constitutes the bulk of our corporate sector.


Investment vehicles in the private equity sector tend to be structured as limited partnerships with a fixed life agreed upfront (this is typically seven to ten years, although allowing for possible roll-over (extension periods)). The partnerships comprise of investors – typically pension funds, university and family endowments



23                    In this context, Ash Demiriguc-Kunt and Ross Levine make the point that “Powerful banks frequently stymie innovation and competition. Banks may extract information rents from firms and thereby reduce the incentives of firms to undertake profitable projects… Furthermore, powerful bankers may collude with managers against other outside investors and thereby thwart competition, efficient resource allocation, and growth.” Ash Demiriguc-Kunt and Ross Levine, Financial Structure and Economic Growth, pg 8. Also see Raghuram G. Rajan, Insiders and outsiders: The choice between informed and arms length debt, (Journal of Finance 47 (4) (September 1992): pgs 1367-1400.


16




and rich individuals – who are the “limited partners” (LPs) and a fund manager, referred to in the industry as the “General Partner”.


ICFC was an early predecessor of today’s PE funds. It carried out a function of national significance, intermediating between small- and medium-sized business, the capital markets and the British government.


When it was founded, ICFC was envisaged as a long overdue response to the 1931 Report of the Committee on Finance and Industry which had been chaired by Lord Macmillan.24. The Macmillan Report (as it was known) highlighted what it saw as the persistent failure of the financial markets and the banking system in Britain to provide long-term investment funds to smaller- and medium-sized companies. This market failure became known as the “Macmillan Gap”. and there are parallels to be drawn between the Report’s analysis of post-1930s Britain and today. For me, the question is whether the financial innovations which arose out of these debates in the 1930s are relevant and applicable today, particularly across Africa where the level of support that the capital markets give to industry is still in its infancy.


The years 2008 and 2009 are not the first time that bankers have come under criticism for the absence of support to industry. Richard Coopey and Donald Clarke in their 1995 history of 3i make the following observation:


“          The relationship between the finance sector and British industry has come under a great deal of scrutiny during the twentieth century. As the British economy, pre-eminent in the nineteenth century, has been overtaken by successive rivals, so questions about the role of the banks and capital market in this relative decline have been repeatedly posed. There are, to be sure, a range of other candidates for the post of chief scapegoat – including a growing anti-industrial culture, the costs of being the first industrial power [etc] and a general demise of scientific and technical literacy. Nevertheless the City, which has become colloquial shorthand for the financial system in Britain, remains one of the most prominent targets for criticism25.



What was the solution to this? Well, interestingly, government intervention in the financial sector was contemplated in a manner that sounds very contemporary – very 2009! Again, Coopey and Clarke make the point:


“          As the depression had deepened in the early 1930s, so debate had intensified over the causes of, and possible remedies for, protracted economic failure. This debate included the fundamental question of market forces versus some form of state intervention, and in this context attention began to be focused upon the working of the financial system in Britain”.26


The Committee on Finance and Industry was set up in November 1929, five months after the election of MacDonalds Labour government, to inquire into “banking, finance and credit” in Britain. The Macmillan Committee, as it came to be known, was chaired by Lord Macmillan and included John Maynard Keynes27 and Ernest Bevin. In spite of the wide-ranging remit of the Committee and the breadth of its final report, it became principally remembered for its identification of the Macmillan gap – a chronic shortage of long-term investment capital for Britain’s small- and medium-sized enterprises28. What the Macmillan Committee identified as being a capital



market failure in the UK is no different from what we should expect to find across Africa as a result of the withdrawal of different forms of capital from our industries. This is further exacerbated by the decline in internally generated funds brought about by slower growth.


We should not underestimate the effect of the above on long term investment which brings me to my last and final point:


4. I hope that one of the lasting post-recession innovations in Africa is a renewed focus on innovations which strengthen the capabilities within our financial sector for long term investments. I know a number of you are Central Bankers and Although you may be focused on questions of disclosure and regulation, I encourage you to also look into the role that the Bank of England played in the emergence of ICFC29 and the problems that Economists such as Keynes addressed through the deliberations of the Macmillan Committee. I hope that you, and other professional economists, will look deeper into the role that the UK’s Central Bank played in encouraging the emergence of this important institution after the 1930s Depression as a way of addressing market failures and the persistant lack of support for industry by the financial sector in Africa. An institution similar to ICFC is an important financial innovation. Today, ICFC has evolved into 3i and plays a role well beyond that confined to providing finance to small and medium sized enterprises. The origins of this institution, born out of the debates amongst economists and policy makers in the 1930s should be of immediate interest to us as we think through the post-recession innovations for today’s world30. Will the 2008/2009 recession lead

to the creation of similar institutions, underpinned by sound economics and by a clear understanding of how markets work? If so, what role can those of you here play through your respective central banks in encouraging the emergence of these institutions across Africa? I have a fear that this recession will see the re-emergence of the Development Banks and an increase in the influence of the DFIs with all the anti-market practices associated with “development financing”. This will be the wrong response and I hope that some of you will do your best to see that this does not happen.


The four points that I have made in these concluding remarks will, I hope stimulate some thought. It is important that our Central Bankers31 and professional economists don’t sit on the sidelines as observers during this most challenging of times. I encourage you to use your time at this conference to think about the post recession world and about your role in it. It is an important role which, to quote President Bush, should not be “mis-underestimated”.


Thank you.



















21 

















What are Bankers for…..?



Keynote speech – CSAE Annual Conference
Africa and the Banking Crisis


St. Catherine’s College, Oxford March 2009




Kofi Adjepong- Boateng*










*          A version of this presentation was made to conference participants and has been amended following discussions at the conference. The author is an investment banker and Senior Associate Member of St. Antony’s College, Oxford. Prior to co-founding First Africa in 1996, he worked in the corporate finance, trade finance and government advisory fields in Africa with SG Warburg & Co., HSBC Equator and Price Waterhouse. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, he was involved in a number of sovereign debt buy-backs, corporate restructurings and commodity financings which occurred in Africa; and since the late 1990s, he has advised on several of Africa’s largest corporate transactions.

During 2003 and 2004, he served on the Africa Policy Advisory Panel, an advisory group mandated by the U.S. Congress, which reported to Colin Powell, the U.S. Secretary of State. He currently serves as a member of the Policy Committee of The Centre for the Study of African Economies (CSAE) and sits on CSAE’s Finance Committee. He is also a member of the Steering Committee of a research project at the Lauterpacht Centre for International Law at the University of Cambridge which is looking into the legal issues associated with accusations of corporate complicity in human rights abuse in resource rich countries. Since 2006, he has served on the International Advisory Board of ACE Ltd, the world’s largest insurer of political risk.

He is a Fellow of the Royal Society of Arts and Manufacturers in the UK and a Member of the UK’s Royal Economic Society.






1





Introductory remarks


I am grateful to Paul, Stefan and the Centre for inviting me here this morning to give this opening address.


I suppose I ought to tell you a bit about myself. I grew up in Ghana, studied at this University many years ago, and have spent my entire career in investment banking. I spent the early part of my career working in London on corporate and sovereign restructurings (including debt restructurings and early privatisations). In 1993, I set up an investment bank in Kenya called Loita Capital Partners which I left in 1995. In 1996, about 13 years ago, a colleague and I established a joint venture investment bank with S.G Warburg & Co. which was at the time the UKs largest and most successful investment bank. That firm, First Africa, was recently acquired by the Standard Chartered Bank group. Standard Chartered has built one of the largest banking operations in Africa over the last 150 years.


I should state upfront that I don’t know very much about what most of you know a lot about. I am not a professional economist; nor am I a civil servant active in policy formation. However, I do know something about “money” and about why, from time to time, it moves from one place to another.. This is probably why I have been asked by Stefan to speak on Africa and the banking crisis”. It seems to me there that are two ways to approach this subject.


One way is to discuss the likely effects on the continent’s growth of the reduction in imports by Africa’s trading partners or the effects on Africa’s trade finance of either a contraction in, or rise of the costs of, global trade finance as international banks come under pressure to focus on their home markets1. I could, for example, talk about the effects of a fall in commodity prices on Africa’s growth. In his recent article in this month’s edition of the UK’s Prospect magazine, Paul Collier estimates that over 200,000 jobs have been lost in the DRC as a result of the collapse in cobalt prices and that South Africa is expecting to lose around 50,000 jobs in its mining sector2. Slow


2




global growth will have implications for African growth and there is quite a bit that one could say about this aspect of the global crisis. But, judging by the quality of this audience, you have probably forgotten more than I will ever know about the inter-relationship between global economic growth and Africa’s trade fortunes. For this reason, I will not spend any time this morning talking to you about this as I feel I can add little to your understanding of this area of international economics and trade. Instead, I have prepared a short slide presentation which is available as a take away and will be sent by Rose Page, Pauls assistant, to each of you by email. It contains a number of the statistics which highlight the current global predicament. What these statistics show in summary is that we are in a very deep global recession comparable by economic historians to the 1930s Depression in certain of its characteristics and from which no country in Africa is immune. No matter how long I take to say this that will be my conclusion so it makes sense to state this conclusion up front and move on.


The second approach to tackling this topic is to ask the question: “What should we (and by that I mean “you and I”) focus on to prepare African policy makers for a post-recession world knowing the likely effects that this global slowdown will have on African economies?” I’d like to find a way in these opening remarks to combine my experience as an investment banker with yours as central bankers and research economists and to see whether there are areas of mutual interest to which we should give attention in the next few months and years in order to ensure that some good comes out of the banking crisis for the benefit of the poor, the middle class and (dare I say it) the rich who inhabit our continent.


One of the advantages about giving a talk to an academic audience is the comfort of knowing that all the parties present are here, not only to share what they know, but also to find out what they don’t know. “Not knowing” at conferences like this is almost as important as “knowing”. I want to spend some time this morning talking about what we do know, but also, would like to invite you, the audience, at the end of this session to help, through questions, shape a research agenda to address what we “don’t know” but should. In this context, the comment that what I have to say “raises more questions than answers” will be seen, by me at least, as a compliment!


I suppose I ought to say upfront that I will be drawing on certain aspects of the history of economics to draw some of my conclusions. This is an important point as, given the current state of the world economy, we are hearing a lot about “history” in general and the 1930s Depression in particular. I recognise the importance in the social sciences of the separation nowadays between “economic history” and “economic theory”.Unlike some, I have always felt that this separation is unfortunate and one of the benefits, if one can describe it as such, of the current crisis is the fact that a lot of the commentary on the current state of affairs is drawing somewhat liberally on economic history as well as the history of economic thought3.


3 Partha Dasgupta draws attention to this unfortunate separation between economic theory and econom ic history in the introduction to a paper presented in 1998. He writes: “You can emerge from your graduate studies in economics without having read any of the classics, or indeed, without having anything other than a vague notion of what the great thinkers of the past had written. The modern economist doesn’t even try to legitimize his inquiry by linking it to questions addressed in the canon; he typically begins his article by referring to something in the literature a few months old. He reads Ricardo no more than the contemporary physicist reads James Clerk Maxwell. What today’s economic student gets of the classics are those bits that have survived the textbook treatment, dressed in modern garb. The history of economic ideas hasn’t died; it has simply metamorphosed into a specialized field.


3






I have been an investment banker for over twenty years. In that period, my career has been influenced by:


-                       the “Third World debt” crisis which had its origins in the Mexican default in 1982. My career started in 1988 about 6 years after the onset of the Mexican crisis. Not surprisingly, all of my assignments in the early days were related in some way to the restructuring African sovereign debt;
-                       the stock market crash of 1987;
-                       the US savings and loan debacle; -     the Asian crisis;
-                       the Russian crisis and the implosion of LTCM; -        the tech bubble of 2000; and now
-                       the current global financial crisis.


That’s seven events of global financial significance all of which occurred in the last twenty-five or so years. Each event taught us important lessons and gave rise to academic research and a body of literature that is still contributing to our understanding today of how financial markets work.


First Africa, the firm I co-founded, has been fortunate to have had a ring-side seat during this in which the African capital markets have grown and evolved rapidly. We have had extraordinary people work with the firm during this time, all of whom were involved in ground-breaking transactions. Some of the precedents in which the firm has been involved include:


-           The sale by Anglo American Corporation in 1995 of JCI Limited to a Black Economic Empowerment consortium in South Africa. At the time, JCI was the world’s sixth largest gold company and the transaction was the most important of the BEE mining transactions completed in South Africa in that year;


-           The sale by the Anglo American Group in 1996 of its interest in First Merchant Bank of Zimbabwe. This was one of the first “empowerment” transactions in Zimbabwe and led to the creation of what has become one of Southern Africa’s important regional banking groups, the African Banking Corporation;


-           In 1999, we acted as an adviser on the takeover of the Cotton Company of Zimbabwe by a private equity consortium. This transaction involved the takeover of what was at the time Zimbabwes largest agricultural company;



It is taught, but it is not compulsory for students, at least not in the major economics departments. And just as most working economists today know little of the ideas that have shaped their subject, your average historian of economic thought understands little of what is currently going on in economics and why. The separation is as complete as can be” Partha Dasgupta, Modern Economics and its Critics I, St. John’s College (February 1998) University of Cambridge, England.


4




-           In 2003, we acted on the sale of the Social Security Bank in Ghana to Frances Societe Generale. This transaction involved us in what became the first takeover of a listed bank anywhere in sub-Saharan Africa;


-           In 2004, the firm acted as an adviser to Anglogold on its merger with Ashanti Goldfields Company. This merger created Africa’s largest gold company. The transaction was accompanied by the dual listing of the merged entity in South Africa and Ghana and remains to date, the largest takeover of a listed West African company;


-           In 2005, we acted on the reverse takeover of African Gold by Mwana Resources and the listing of Mwana on AIM in London. Reversing predominantly Zimbabwean assets in a London listed vehicle is difficult at the best of times. To do so at the height of the Zimbabwean crisis was ground breaking in its own right;


-           In 2006, we advised the MTN Group on its acquisition of Investcom LLC. This was one of the most important cross-border takovers by a South African company and at the time, was the second largest transaction of its kind in South Africa. It was also the first takeover of a company listed on the Dubai Stock Exchange and is still the only successful transaction of this size completed by either of the leading South Africa telecoms companies;


-           We acted on the conversion of Equity Building Society in East Africa from a mutual society into a bank and the listing of Equity Bank on the Nairobi Stock Exchange. This transaction was the first of its kind in East Africa and has since become the precedent for those considering transactions of this kind; and


-           More recently, we acted in 2008 and early this year on the Rights Issue and Placing undertaken by ETI, the West African regional banking group. This transaction raised a significant sum for the bank and was executed during the still ongoing global financial crisis. ETI raised what amounted the largest pool of capital raised by any firm on the Ghana Stock Exchange, which is one of the West African exchanges on which the bank is listed.


The above list illustrates the breadth of work carried out by firms such as mine in Africa. There are many other transactions which could be added to this list but I believe the short list above illustrates the extent to which financial services companies such as ours play an important role in facilitating the corporate activity in Africa. The question worth considering is the extent to which this level of corporate activity took place primarily because of financial innovations in Africa and elsewhere. Innovations such as the introduction of stock markets, the role played by private equity and hedge funds in investing in African companies and the emergence of cross-border financial players who have been able to help ensure that standardised and good quality financial information becomes available outside of national borders are all important




5




financial innovations whose role in spawning cross-border corporate activity should not be underestimated.


Over time, today’s crisis will give rise to robust debate amongst professional economists such as you about the policy prescriptions for a post-recession world and I would like to use these opening remarks to ask that you start thinking about areas for further research which will make more robust about our approach to policy. That’s my objective this morning.


So, What are Bankers for…(in theory!)


Many economists, and I hope the majority of you here, view freely operating markets in which free exchange occurs as the best mechanism for allocating scarce resources. From the point of view of allocating capital, the most important markets in this respect are the commercial banking market, stock exchange (or stock market) and other capital markets, such as the bond market or the markets in other financial securities.


I share the view that the capital markets are crucial for the allocation of resources in a modern economy. Household savings are channelled through the capital markets to the corporate sector and investment funds are allocated, again through the markets, among companies. Markets allow both companies and households to share risks, or so we believe. I am conscious that there have been recent lessons learnt about risk sharing as a result of the predicament in which giant global financial services companies such as AIG find themselves. But for now, I will restate my belief that well functioning capital markets enable both firms and households to share risks.


However, having said this, it seems to me on reading the literature that there are at least four important limitations to the efficiency with which capital markets operate, particularly in Africa and other emerging markets:


1. Firstly, in most countries, such as those in Africa, stock markets are not that large or important. The financial markets in Africa and other emerging markets are primarily markets for government debt. Often, the external capital that industry requires for investment is obtained in the form of loans directly from commercial banks;


2. Secondly, in all countries, including the US and UK, internally generated funds tend to be more important than is frequently acknowledged. In most African countries these internally generated funds are far more important than the external finance raised through the capital markets and commercial banks. This has certain implications which I will come back to;


3. Thirdly, the ideal of a frictionless capital market is rarely, if ever, achieved in practice. Financial intermediaries, such as stock brokers, investment and merchant banks like ours, are needed to overcome the barriers to information and to market participation. Reducing these informational barriers is important if firms and investors are to exploit markets effectively; and





6




4. Finally, we should not underestimate how important it is to well functioning capital markets that there is also an effective market in corporate control (in other words, a market in takeovers or mergers). Most of my career has been spent in the market for corporate control. This is an important aspect of the role played by the capital markets which must not be forgotten. Corporate takeovers are not as common in Africa as they are elsewhere in the world, but they are becoming more common. The possibility of takeovers is assumed to be a device for disciplining managers. An acquirer can buy up the shares of a badly managed target, replace the incumbent management, better utilise the company’s assets and make a capital gain. The capital markets are meant to play an important oversight role, but we should not ignore the equal importance of the role played in asset allocation by the threat and presence of corporate takovers.


Despite the limitations listed above, there is almost universal popularity of capital markets across the world4. To date, several African countries have introduced legislation to encourage the emergence of stock exchanges and a number of African countries have recently tapped the international bond markets. One of First Africa’s board directors, Walter Kansteiner, put in place a program when he was President Bush’s Assistant Secretary of State for Africa to encourage the rating of African sovereign bonds. Between March 2004 and February 2009, eight African countries, all of which benefited under the Kansteiner program and secured ratings, raised over US$16 billion in the international bond markets.


There are two important reasons why there is almost universal popularity of capital markets across the world. One reason is what I call the “push” factor and the other, the “pull” factor:


1. Firstly, government intervention has become discredited. The appeal of government intervention in the 1950s and 1960s had its origins in the market failures associated with the 1929 Wall Street crash and the Great Depression of the 1930s. This is an important point as it serves as a reminder that this is not the first time that a global financial crisis has led to calls for greater government intervention and regulation. Prior to the onset of the current global financial crisis, it appeared to many people that government failures are at least as important, if not more important, a problem as market failures. This is what I would call the “push” factor underpinning the popularity of the free market in general, and of capital markets in particular. The current crisis may have damped the public’s enthusiasm for free markets. Bank nationalisation in the West has been taken in its stride;


2. The second reason for the universal popularity of capital markets is that policy makers have been persuaded by economic theorists to promote free markets. Economic theory, particularly that pertaining to financial markets, has stressed the effectiveness of markets in allocating resources. This is what I would call

the “pull factor”. The general acceptance by policy makers of free markets as “efficient” markets was predominately a backlash against the views of Keynes which had initially dominated the post-war era. The intellectual attractiveness of efficient markets had a lot to do with the works of Milton Friedman, Robert Lucas and Eugene Fama. Works with which I’m sure you are all familiar.5


As economists, you are looking to understand the role that financial markets play in different national economies. As economists, you bring to your task an intellectual training that places markets at the very centre of the study of economics. Some of you might even go so far as to argue that markets define the very subject matter of economics and that complete and competitive markets represent the ideal allocation system backed up by the fundamental theorems of welfare economics.


Having said this, I am sure that most of you will recognise that there are a number of areas of study and research that have become an increasingly important part of economics in the past few decades. The current global crisis reminds us of how important these areas of study are:


1.         Firstly, there are the incentive problems that arise between agents and principals, employers and employees, managers and shareholders, financial institutions and their customers;
2.         Secondly, there are difficulties that arise in financial markets when information is asymmetrically distributed. The early work of Joe Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss helped formulate our early understanding of these issues6;
3.         Thirdly, there are always transaction costs. That’s how I have earned my living for several years. It is these transaction costs which prevent the existence of more than a small fraction of the number of possible


5                      For a discussion on the emergence of Chicago economics and the role that this school played in the providing the theoretical underpinnings to deregulation see Johan Van Overtveldt, The Chicago School How the University of Chicago Assembled the Thinkers who Revolutionized Economics and Business (Agate, 2007) and Craig F. Freedman, Chicago Fundamentalism Ideology and Methodology in Economics (World Scientific Publishing Co. (2008)). The views of the Chicago School differed radically from those of Keynes which had dominated the post-War era. Peter Clark’s review of Robert Skidelsky’s biographies of Keynes reminds us how different these two schools actually were”Skidelsky is against the single-book” interpretation of Keynesianism, and thus demands due attention for the Treatise [on Money]. Its message is that savings and investment, being different activities carried on by different people, could not simply be presumed identical. It took interest rate to bring them into equilibrium. …What Skidelsky …. chooses to emphasize is the Treatise’s preoccupation with the economics of disequilibrium, when the economy is in a position of sub-optimal output and hence unemployment. If the Bank rate …is what restores equilibrium, it follows that banking policy plays a crucial role in stabilizing the system. “Order has to be created”, is Skidelsky’s gloss; “it is not natural. Put like thisthe Treatise carries us a long way into the world disclosed by the General Theory, in which the absence of any self-righting forces in the economy is affirmed” – Peter Clark, Keynes rediscovered, Times Literary Supplement (November 20, 1992) pg 4. This is a point on which Clark had elaborated upon in his earlier and more extensive work: The Keynesian Revolution in the Making 1924-1936 (Oxford University Press (1988)) See for example pages 22-24.

6                       See, for example, J. Stiglitz and A. Weiss, Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information, (American Economic Review, 71 (3) (June) 1981;



8




markets envisaged by the Arrow-Debreu-Mackenzie general equilibrium models7;
4.         Finally, there are the long-term relationships between financial institutions and our customers which, from time to time, stifle competition and almost certainly counter any view that “perfect competition” exists.


The four areas of study listed above are central to our understanding of finance today, since much of financial practice and theory deals with the attempt to overcome agency problems, incomplete markets, transaction costs, and lack of information. Work done by two of CSAE’s Directors, Stefan Dercon on insurance markets and Marcel Fafchamps on market institutions, both highlight the shortcomings of markets and how these limitations influence institutional developments8.


Despite the above limitations, the classical theory makes a powerful case for the role that markets play in national economies whenever the imperfections caused by market power, asymmetric information, and incentive problems are not too overbearing. However, the fact that we are living through a global crisis which has largely been caused by a wide range of market failures (particularly as they relate to the incentive problems in the banking industry) is a very rude reminder of the limitations of markets.


So, why is understanding these limitations important to understanding the likely impact of the global recession on Africa’s growth?


To begin to understand the likely impact of the global crisis on Africa, one must start with an understanding of the relationship between the financial system of a country and the real economy and in particular the corporate sector.


Companies are the issuers of all of the securities traded in the capital markets outside of government paper and the investment return on these securities depend on the performance of the issuers that make up the corporate sector. The financial sector plays an important role in corporate governance because it allocates control rights (including rights over cash flows) and assists in the design of the securities that are issued. Once securities are issued, it is the financial intermediaries who provide information on company performance that investors utilise to make decisions on whether to buy or sell securities.

9





As mentioned earlier, the market for corporate control simply does not exist in most African countries, and the evidence for the monitoring role of banks over African corporates is weak. In addition, the reliance on internal finance by African corporates means that managers are largely autonomous of outside sources of capital. African firms, particularly the large diversified companies such as Dangote Industries in Nigeria or the Anglo American Group in South Africa can act as financial institutions to compensate for the limitations of financial markets and financial intermediaries. I have not as yet seen any research from you or your peers on the efficiency of capital allocation decisions made by our African conglomerates either historically (as companies such as Anglo can no longer be called conglomerates in the classical sense of the word) or presently (and here I’m thinking of the likes of Dangote in Nigeria, Press Holdings in Malawi or the various East African groups). Perhaps, this is one of the research takeaways that will come out of this conference9. I hope so.


Where capital markets are robust and deep, it is reasonable to assume that companies pay all their earnings to their shareholders and that the capital markets and the banking sector provide firms with the capital required for investment. In practice, however, features such as asymmetric information and agency costs restrict the role of external finance. This makes raising external capital a costly alternative to internally generated funds.


In several markets, including those in Africa, the development of the capital markets was stunted by the frequency with which governments print money. By printing money, governments avoided the need to issue paper which is an important component in the development of any capital markets. The inflationary effects of excesses in money supply also discouraged the purchase of long term securities. For this reason, companies operating in Africa have historically been forced to rely on internal finance as a more important source of funds than debt or equity for long term investment as the issue of long dated securities simply does not happen. The problem with this state of affairs is that there does not seem to me to be a robust reason for believing that the allocation of funds for investment that results from the use of






internally generated capital is optimal. Firms that are cash rich may be poor in opportunities for investment and vice versa and so the external finance constraint (in other words, the absence of properly functioning capital markets) appears to be a source of inefficiency. As credit becomes scarce, this problem is exacerbated. An efficient market in corporate control reduces this constraint by enabling cash rich firms to buy firms with little cash and cash poor firms to sell themselves to those with more cash. My point here is that the fact that we are beginning to see a rise in corporate takeovers and merger activity in Africa supported by the role played by investment bankers means that some of the limitations our countries face as a result of not having very deep capital markets may now start to be addressed. Research done in this area in Africa may also give rise to some interesting results and I would encourage this as another takeaway from this conference.


So what do Bankers do…(in practice!)?


The points made above highlight the importance of the role played by financial intermediaries. Despite what you might read about investment bankers, we actually do serve a useful purpose, once in a while. Financial intermediaries, (people like me), are becoming increasingly essential to the efficient exploitation of complex capital markets.


The role of financial intermediaries such as investment bankers is to make it possible for individuals to gain some of the benefits of complex financial markets without bearing all of the prohibitive costs that come with a high level of sophistication. These benefits in part arise by economizing on the costs of acquiring information. This is the traditional advising role of intermediaries such as investment bankers. The intermediary acquires information at a fixed cost and shares it with its customers at a nominal marginal cost.


Without intermediaries, the full benefits of financial innovation will not flow through to the economy at large, either globally or locally.


The analysis of the benefits to economic growth of a well-functioning financing system has a long history with a growing body of academic research arguing that the development of financial markets and institutions within countries and across borders is a critical part of the growth process and not simply an inconsequential spill over responding passively to economic growth and industrialization. Research in this area can be traced back to Walter Bagehot whose seminal work was published in 187310. The work done by Sir John Hicks in interpreting various aspects of economic history11 and by Ronald McKinnon12 on the role of capital in economic development follows this tradition. More recent research work has been carried out by several others13. This literature describes the way financial systems reduce information and

transaction costs and in so doing influence savings rates, investment decisions, technological innovations, long-run growth rates and the rate of industrialization.


Economists hold very divergent opinions on the importance of the financial system for economic growth. Walter Bagehot (1873) and Sir John Hicks (1969) argue that it played a critical role in igniting industrialisation in England by facilitating the mobilisation of capital for (what John Hicks called) “immense works”. Sir John argued that the capital market improvements that mitigated liquidity risk were the primary causes of the industrial revolution in England14. With liquid capital markets, savers can hold assets – such as equities or bonds – that they can sell quickly and easily if they want access to their savings. Simultaneously, capital markets transform these liquid financial assets into long-term capital investments in illiquid production processes. John Hicks believed that because the industrial revolution required large commitments of capital for long periods, the transformation in industry in England may not have occurred without this liquidity transformation brought about by financial innovation.


Another economist of old, Joseph Schumpeter made the point in 1912 that a well-functioning capital market spurs technological innovation by identifying and funding those ideas with the best chance of successfully implementing innovative products and/or production processes.


In contrast, Joan Robinson at Cambridge wrote in 1952 that she believed that “where enterprise leads finance follows”. According to this view, economic development creates demands for particular types of financial arrangements, and the financial system responds automatically to these demands. From what I have witnessed in my career, I am more persuaded by the views of John Hicks on the role of financial intermediaries than I am by those of Joan Robinson on this subject15. This is a point to which I will return in my conclusion.





Money, Credit, Banking, August 1988 pp 559-88; and Franklin Allen and Douglas Gale, Comparing Financial Systems, MIT Press (2000).

14                     Hicks tells readers that: “My Theory of Economic History is largely an attempt to see the main lines of economic development as a matter of the evolution of the merchant-intermediary, and its consequences”; John Hicks: The Formation of an Economist. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, September, 1979.

15                    Joan Robinson’s own views on Hick’s work are perhaps partly summarised in the following quote: “Whenever equilibrium theory is breached, economists rush like bees whose comb has been broken to patch up the damage. J. R. Hicks was one of the first, with his IS/LM, to try to reduce the General Theory to a system of equilibrium. This had a wide success and has distorted teaching for many generations of students. J.R.Hicks used to be fond of quoting a letter from Keynes which, because of its friendly tone, seemed to approve of IS/LM, but it contained a clear objection to a system that leaves out expectations of the future from the inducements to invest…Forty years later, John Hicks noticed the difference between the future and the past and became dissatisfied with IS/LM but (presumably to save face for his predecessor, J.R.) he argued that Keynes’s analysis was only half in time and half in equilibrium” Joan Robinson, Further Contributions to Modern Economics (Basil Blackwell (1980)) pg 79.



12





Where to from here?


To my mind, taking the points I have made this morning, the current global crisis does give us a firm basis for thinking about a research agenda into the functioning of the banking and broader financial markets in Africa. It is towards this research agenda that I would like to make some suggestions.


I will make a number of points in summary form and I trust that as I do so, you remember my earlier plea for the compliment that “I have raised more questions than answers”!:


1.         Firstly, the current global crisis has given rise to significant state ownership of, or investment in, a number of the leading global banks which are active in trade and corporate finance in Africa. The likes of Citibank, Royal Bank of Scotland and Fortis will find that they come under pressure to focus on their home markets in the US, UK and Europe. Any expansion of their activities in emerging markets such as Africa will be curtailed. The likes of Barclays may not have taken state aid to date, but I expect them and those of the other banks which may also not have taken state aid to nonetheless come under pressure from their respective governments to focus on business in their home markets. For the past two centuries, much of the flow of investment capital into Africa and other emerging markets has been dominated by international merchant banks. It is these banks which shaped the early pattern of global investment into Africa. A fair amount of research exists at present on the nature of, and mechanisms for, investment made through the British capital markets into Argentina, Australia, Canada, and the United States16 but less so in the case of Africa. The four countries mentioned above are estimated to account for about one-half of British overseas finance, were frontier territories whose development depended on their ability to bring new lands and natural resources within the scope of the international market. In this respect, these colonies were no different from those in Africa. To facilitate the economic development of the Americas and Australia, it was necessary to invest in transport, mining, land development, agriculture, agricultural and mineral processing, as well as services and products which supported colonial development. While research into these four territories exists, there has been very little research on the nature of investment into Africa during the colonial period. In this regard, it is worthwhile drawing attention to the similar historical role that the merchant banks17, such as


16                     See Lance E. Davis and Robert E. Gallman: Evolving Financial Markets and International Capital Flows- Britain, The Americas, and Australia, 1865-1914. Cambridge University Press. (2001).

17                    The definition of what constituted a “merchant bank” during the 19th Century is itself an area of some debate. Geoffrey Jones, writing on this subject, notes as follows: “The relationship between trading companies and banks was both multifaceted and highly significant for both parties. …[I]n their origins merchants and bankers were virtually indistinguishable, and it was only slowly over the course of the nineteenth century that a clearer separation occurred. In several cases, such as Anthony Gibbs, Wallace Brothers, and Mathesons, merchant banking remained part of the business portfolio. Matheson & Co. regarded its legal status in a


13




Baring Brothers & Co., N.M. Rothschild & Sons and J. Henry Schroder & Co18., played in the colonial era in facilitating capital flows into Africa as well as the role played by other members of the London Stock Exchange19. The flow of capital into Africa and other colonial territories facilitated by the London firms was the building block for today’s global financial architecture and an important component of global financial flows which continues to remain in place today20.


The withdrawal of the global banks from building their business aggressively in Africa and other emerging markets will make room for local banks to expand and capture market share. How local firms behave in the face of less competition from foreign firms will be important in

determining how deep the provision of financial services in Africa continues to become.. Will the less competitive landscape locally for both management talent and customers mean that we will see local banks expand into disciplines like project finance and corporate finance which have been the domain of foreign banks? Will they attempt to expand their product offering to the unbanked market on the back of the rising profitability of their core businesses? How prepared are our central banks to regulate the movement by our local banks into areas such as project and acquisition finance and securities (margin) lending? All these areas of banking have in the past been dominated by foreign firms.


2.         Secondly, there will be a decline in the overseas interest in acquiring African corporate assets as a result of the crisis. Over the past few years, my firm and others have seen an increase in cross-border acquisitions. The slides you will be receiving after this presentation set out data on mergers and acquisitions. Interest has been led by Asian buyers. For example, following the withdrawal of Anglo American from the Zambian Copperbelt in the early 1990s, we saw the fortunes of the Copperbelt transformed by the likes of First Quantum, Equinox and Vadanta all junior mining companies with origins in Australasia. As I explained earlier, mergers and acquisitions play an important role in unlocking corporate assets and from time to time play the efficiency role that the lack of depth in the capital markets leaves unfilled. If, as expected, the global slowdown reduces the ability of financial intermediaries to facilitate activity in Africa’s corporate sector by overseas buyers, will our capital markets respond with enough acumen to support acquisitions by our local players as they look to take advantage lower prices for corporate assets due to lower foreign interest? Again, are our regulators sufficiently tuned into the benefits of corporate consolidation and the role that our local financial services companies are to play in this area? The ties between international investment, economic growth and the role of financial intermediaries in the 19th and early 20th centuries is well documented21. These functions include facilitating the trading of risk, allocating capital between Great Britain and its colonies in Africa, monitoring managers such as Cecil John Rhodes and the United Africa Company, mobilizing savings in Britain for investment overseas, and easing the trading of goods, services, and financial contracts across borders22. In understanding these ties, it is


important to point out that academic economists and historians have highlighted some of the shortcomings associated with the role played by banks in resource allocation. The potential for banks to extract oligopolistic rents from industry is already the subject of research23.Nonetheless, the role played by investment banks is central to a well functioning M&A market and it will be important to see whether as there is a reduction in the number of foreign buyers active in Africas corporate market, the large local and regional players become more active, with support from the local African financial markets.


3.         Thirdly, the global slowdown will limit the growth by Africa’s local corporates of internally generated earnings. As mentioned earlier, retained earnings are an important, though not perfect, substitute for a deep capital market. Because of this, my expectation is that the effects of slower corporate earnings growth will translate into slower long term investment. Our financial markets are not yet deep enough to step into this gap and in the absence of alternatives, we should expect the current crisis to lead to a slow down in the very forms of long term investment that Africa needs. This need not be the case and before I conclude these opening remarks, I would like to spend a few minutes talking about one of the financial innovations that arose out of the 1930s Depression. It is a good guide to the influence that economists and Central Bankers can have on a post-recession world.,


My comments are on a company called Industrial and Commercial Finance Corporation (otherwise known as “ICFC”). It was formed in the UK after the 1930s depression. I have a soft spot for ICFC as my father worked there after his undergraduate degree at Wharton.


ICFC, was, in essence, what we would today call a “venture capital fund”. It has since evolved into 3i, a “private equity fund” and although I recognise the difference between the two types of institutions, the points that I would like to make in this presentation are common to both “venture capital” and “private equity” and so, for this reason, I will refer to the whole asset class as “private equity”.


Private Equity consists of equity investments in companies that are not listed on a stock exchange. For Africa, this constitutes the bulk of our corporate sector.


Investment vehicles in the private equity sector tend to be structured as limited partnerships with a fixed life agreed upfront (this is typically seven to ten years, although allowing for possible roll-over (extension periods)). The partnerships comprise of investors – typically pension funds, university and family endowments



23                    In this context, Ash Demiriguc-Kunt and Ross Levine make the point that “Powerful banks frequently stymie innovation and competition. Banks may extract information rents from firms and thereby reduce the incentives of firms to undertake profitable projects… Furthermore, powerful bankers may collude with managers against other outside investors and thereby thwart competition, efficient resource allocation, and growth.” Ash Demiriguc-Kunt and Ross Levine, Financial Structure and Economic Growth, pg 8. Also see Raghuram G. Rajan, Insiders and outsiders: The choice between informed and arms length debt, (Journal of Finance 47 (4) (September 1992): pgs 1367-1400.


16




and rich individuals – who are the “limited partners” (LPs) and a fund manager, referred to in the industry as the “General Partner”.


ICFC was an early predecessor of today’s PE funds. It carried out a function of national significance, intermediating between small- and medium-sized business, the capital markets and the British government.


When it was founded, ICFC was envisaged as a long overdue response to the 1931 Report of the Committee on Finance and Industry which had been chaired by Lord Macmillan.24. The Macmillan Report (as it was known) highlighted what it saw as the persistent failure of the financial markets and the banking system in Britain to provide long-term investment funds to smaller- and medium-sized companies. This market failure became known as the “Macmillan Gap”. and there are parallels to be drawn between the Report’s analysis of post-1930s Britain and today. For me, the question is whether the financial innovations which arose out of these debates in the 1930s are relevant and applicable today, particularly across Africa where the level of support that the capital markets give to industry is still in its infancy.


The years 2008 and 2009 are not the first time that bankers have come under criticism for the absence of support to industry. Richard Coopey and Donald Clarke in their 1995 history of 3i make the following observation:


“          The relationship between the finance sector and British industry has come under a great deal of scrutiny during the twentieth century. As the British economy, pre-eminent in the nineteenth century, has been overtaken by successive rivals, so questions about the role of the banks and capital market in this relative decline have been repeatedly posed. There are, to be sure, a range of other candidates for the post of chief scapegoat – including a growing anti-industrial culture, the costs of being the first industrial power [etc] and a general demise of scientific and technical literacy. Nevertheless the City, which has become colloquial shorthand for the financial system in Britain, remains one of the most prominent targets for criticism25.



What was the solution to this? Well, interestingly, government intervention in the financial sector was contemplated in a manner that sounds very contemporary – very 2009! Again, Coopey and Clarke make the point:


“          As the depression had deepened in the early 1930s, so debate had intensified over the causes of, and possible remedies for, protracted economic failure. This debate included the fundamental question of market forces versus some form of state intervention, and in this context attention began to be focused upon the working of the financial system in Britain”.26


The Committee on Finance and Industry was set up in November 1929, five months after the election of MacDonalds Labour government, to inquire into “banking, finance and credit” in Britain. The Macmillan Committee, as it came to be known, was chaired by Lord Macmillan and included John Maynard Keynes27 and Ernest Bevin. In spite of the wide-ranging remit of the Committee and the breadth of its final report, it became principally remembered for its identification of the Macmillan gap – a chronic shortage of long-term investment capital for Britain’s small- and medium-sized enterprises28. What the Macmillan Committee identified as being a capital



market failure in the UK is no different from what we should expect to find across Africa as a result of the withdrawal of different forms of capital from our industries. This is further exacerbated by the decline in internally generated funds brought about by slower growth.


We should not underestimate the effect of the above on long term investment which brings me to my last and final point:


4. I hope that one of the lasting post-recession innovations in Africa is a renewed focus on innovations which strengthen the capabilities within our financial sector for long term investments. I know a number of you are Central Bankers and Although you may be focused on questions of disclosure and regulation, I encourage you to also look into the role that the Bank of England played in the emergence of ICFC29 and the problems that Economists such as Keynes addressed through the deliberations of the Macmillan Committee. I hope that you, and other professional economists, will look deeper into the role that the UK’s Central Bank played in encouraging the emergence of this important institution after the 1930s Depression as a way of addressing market failures and the persistant lack of support for industry by the financial sector in Africa. An institution similar to ICFC is an important financial innovation. Today, ICFC has evolved into 3i and plays a role well beyond that confined to providing finance to small and medium sized enterprises. The origins of this institution, born out of the debates amongst economists and policy makers in the 1930s should be of immediate interest to us as we think through the post-recession innovations for today’s world30. Will the 2008/2009 recession lead

to the creation of similar institutions, underpinned by sound economics and by a clear understanding of how markets work? If so, what role can those of you here play through your respective central banks in encouraging the emergence of these institutions across Africa? I have a fear that this recession will see the re-emergence of the Development Banks and an increase in the influence of the DFIs with all the anti-market practices associated with “development financing”. This will be the wrong response and I hope that some of you will do your best to see that this does not happen.


The four points that I have made in these concluding remarks will, I hope stimulate some thought. It is important that our Central Bankers31 and professional economists don’t sit on the sidelines as observers during this most challenging of times. I encourage you to use your time at this conference to think about the post recession world and about your role in it. It is an important role which, to quote President Bush, should not be “mis-underestimated”.


Thank you.


















Labels: , , ,